《战略与企业家综合概述(英文版).docx》由会员分享,可在线阅读,更多相关《战略与企业家综合概述(英文版).docx(43页珍藏版)》请在taowenge.com淘文阁网|工程机械CAD图纸|机械工程制图|CAD装配图下载|SolidWorks_CaTia_CAD_UG_PROE_设计图分享下载上搜索。
1、编号:时间:2021年x月x日书山有路勤为径,学海无涯苦作舟页码:第43页 共43页STRATEGY AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP: OUTLINES OF AN UNTOLD STORYSaras D. SarasvathyUniversity of WashingtonS. VenkataramanUniversity of VirginiaInvited book chapter in the Strategic Management Handbook edited by Hitt et.al.(Revised December 10, 2000) In his book “
2、InventionPage: 2It was Herbs advice not to use “editorial” adjectives while citing a work as far as possible may be the reader thinks it is a mundane piece, for example, why turn the reader off our piece based on differences of opinion about someone we are citing? The key thing is to focus on the ac
3、tual content of the cite and its usefulness in making our point than expressing our enthusiasm for it,” Professor Norbert Wiener (1993), commenting on the relative importance accorded to individuals and institutions in historical narratives of science and inventions, asks us to imagine Shakespeares
4、“Romeo and Juliet” without either Romeo or the balcony. Weiner took his inspiration from the work of the English writer, Rudyard Kipling. The story is just not the same. He likens much of the study of the economic history of science and accounts of inventions as “all balcony and no Romeo.” The balco
5、ny for Norbert Wiener captures the context in which the story unfolds the culture, the institutions, the constraints and the catalysts that move the plot forward and thicken it. Romeos, for Wiener, play the leading parts in the story, because there is a strong fortuitous element to inventions and th
6、ere is no inevitability that a possible discovery will be made at a given time and space. Take away either one, Romeo or the balcony, and the whole story falls apart. In a similar vein, we would liken studies of strategic management to “all balcony and no Romeo.” But if we accuse strategic managemen
7、t of being “all balcony and no Romeo,” strategic management scholars could legitimately accuse entrepreneurship of being “all Romeo and no balcony.” In this chapter we wish to suggest a point of view from entrepreneurship that will allow strategic management scholars to accommodate more Romeos in th
8、eir stories. Although these two fields have much to offer each other (trade in balconies and Romeos), they have developed largely independent of each other. We wish to suggest that entrepreneurship has a role to play in strategic management theory and that strategic management theory enriches our un
9、derstanding of the entrepreneurial process, although this latter aspect will not be the focus of this chapter.One useful way of thinking about entrepreneurship is that it is concerned with understanding how, in the absence of markets for future goods and services, these goods and services manage to
10、come into existence (Venkataraman, 1997). To the extent value is embodied in products and services, entrepreneurship is concerned with how the opportunity to create “value” in society is discovered and acted upon by some individuals. As Wiener has noted (Wiener, 1993: 7), at the beginning stages of
11、a new idea, the effectiveness of the individual is enormous: “Before any new idea can arise in theory and practice, some person or persons must have introduced it in their own minds The absence of original mind, even though it might not have excluded a certain element of progress in the distant futu
12、re, may well delay it for fifty years or a century.” The field of strategic management can be usefully described as having to do with the “methods” used to create this “value” and the ensuing struggle to capture a significant share of that “value” by individuals and firms. Thus, if we understand ent
13、repreneurship and strategic management as the fields that together seek to describe, explain, predict and prescribe how value is discovered, created, captured, and perhaps destroyed, then there is not only much that we can learn from each other, but together we represent two sides of the same coin:
14、the coin of value creation and capture.One side of the coin, namely strategic management, has to do with the achievement of ends obtaining market share, profit, and sustained competitive advantage. The other side of the coin, namely entrepreneurship, has to do with the achievement of beginnings crea
15、ting products, firms, and markets. But the clarity and complexity with which an author connects beginnings and ends is what makes a great story. We believe the really interesting story between strategic management and entrepreneurship has not yet been told. The main reason for this is that in genera
16、l, creation calls for very different modes of thinking and behavior than capture and sustenance over time. Yet the creation process not only determines certain powerful tendencies for survival and growth, but some elements of it also persist over long periods of time, subtly and substantially influe
17、ncing the selection and achievement of later ends. Carefully bearing in mind that large expanses of strategic management may have no overlap with entrepreneurship It is worth pointing out here that when discussing creative processes in the economic domain, strategy is a sub-set of entrepreneurship.
18、For example, for any given new technical invention there are, at least in theory, an infinite number of product possibilities that may flow out of that invention. But, in practice, only a finite sub-set of those possibilities will come into existence. Of those new products that come into existence,
19、only a sub-set is introduced by existing firms. Indeed, a large number of new products are introduced into the economy by new firms. Strategy essentially focuses on existing firms and the activities of existing firms. Entrepreneurship, on the other hand, has been focusing attention on the creative p
20、rocess, particularly of new firms. Where they overlap is at the nexus of the creative process of existing firms. Thus, each field has vast terrains that do not overlap., this chapter nevertheless focuses exclusively on where entrepreneurship and strategic management overlap.In the preface to their 1
21、994 book, Rumelt, Schendel, and Teece identify the subject matter of strategic management as the purposeful direction and natural evolution of enterprises. (Rumelt, et. al., 1994) They further identify four fundamental issues that comprise a research agenda in strategic management:1.Firm Behavior Th
22、e choice of the term firm and the choice of focusing on the pre-existing firm by Rumelt, Schendel, and Teece (1994) only affirm our assertion in the previous footnote.How do firms behave? Or, do firms really behave like rational actors, and, if not, what models of their behavior should be used by re
23、searchers and policy makers?2.Firm DifferentiationWhy are firms different? Or, what sustains the heterogeneity in resources and performance among close competitors despite competition and imitative attempts?3.Firm ScopeWhat is the function of or value added by the headquarters unit in a diversified
24、firm? Or, what limits the scope of the firm?4.Firm PerformanceWhat determines success or failure in international competition? Or, what are the origins of success and what are their particular manifestations in international settings or global competition?In answering the four questions stated above
25、, economics and strategic management theories generally tend to focus on rational decision making (whether unbounded or bounded and linear or non-linear) based on causal reasoning and the logic of prediction. Our explication of entrepreneurship, however, rests upon creative action based on effectual
26、 reasoning and the logic of control.We have elsewhere identified the subject matter of entrepreneurship as having to do with the exploitation of opportunities for creating hitherto non-existent economic artifacts (Venkataraman, 1997; Shane and Venkataraman, 2000; Sarasvathy and Simon, 2000; Sarasvat
27、hy, 2001). Depending upon the completeness and/or consistency of the larger environment, entrepreneurial opportunities may have to be recognized or discovered or created. In this chapter, we first examine these three types of action connected with entrepreneurial opportunities through a framework ba
28、sed on the preconditions for their existence. Thereafter, we explore the four fundamental issues of strategic management listed above from an entrepreneurial opportunity perspective. ENTREPRENEURIAL OPPORTUNITIES This section summarizes our more detailed exposition titled Three views of entrepreneur
29、ial opportunity.The Oxford English Dictionary defines opportunity as “a time, juncture, or condition of things favorable to an end or purpose, or admitting of something being done or effected.” As is clear from this definition, at the minimum, an opportunity involves an end or purpose, and things fa
30、vorable to the achievement of it. An entrepreneurial opportunity consists of the opportunity to create future economic artifacts and as such, involves a demand side, a supply side and the means to bring them together. Therefore, in the case of an entrepreneurial opportunity, the “things favorable” c
31、onsist of two categories: (a) beliefs about the future; and (b) actions based on those beliefs. In sum, an entrepreneurial opportunity consists of:1. Supply side: New or existing idea/s or invention/s;2. Demand side: One or more ends may be subjective (endogenous) aspirations or objective (exogenous
32、) goals or both; The entrepreneur not only has an idea for a product or firm, but also has some personal aspirations and/or goals in pursuing the opportunity. Goals could be as specific as making an IPO in five years to creating a legacy for their children. And aspirations could range from making mo
33、ney to enjoying an independent lifestyle to changing the world. Furthermore, these aspirations and goals could change and new ones could emerge over time. 3. Beliefs about things favorable to the achievement of those ends; and,4. Possible implementations of those ends through the creation of new eco
34、nomic artifacts. At this point, it is important to note that entrepreneurial opportunities exist at all levels of the economy individual, corporate, and macroeconomic. For example, the invention of the internet not only led to the identification and creation of entrepreneurial opportunities for indi
35、viduals and firms, but also opportunities for the US economy as a whole in terms of more effective globalization. Similarly, Adam Smiths exposition of the invisible hand guided both economic policy at the government level as well as the decisions of individual economic agents and firms in the creati
36、on of free market institutions.But entrepreneurial opportunities are extremely context specific. What might be an opportunity today in the Ukraine may not be an opportunity at all in the US today or even in the Ukraine tomorrow. This means that entrepreneurial opportunities do not necessarily lie ar
37、ound waiting to be discovered by the serendipitous entrepreneur who stumbles upon them or even to be “divined” by entrepreneurial geniuses, if any such geniuses exist. Instead, entrepreneurial opportunities are often residuals of human activities in non-economic spheres and emerge contingent upon co
38、nscious actions by entrepreneurs who continually strive to transform the outputs of those non-economic activities into new products and firms and in the process fulfil and transform human aspirations into new markets.In other words, before there are products and firms, there is human imagination; an
39、d before there are markets, there are human aspirations. Creative outputs of the human imagination in every realm of human action be it the arts or the sciences, sports or philosophy, become inputs for the economic domain. It is an empirical fact that profits for the individual and the firm, and wel
40、fare for the economy come as much from Jerry Seinfelds jokes and Michael Jordans baskets, as from great technological inventions and the tearing down of the Berlin wall. Similarly, human aspirations may range from career goals and individual prosperity to freedom and justice and the good life for al
41、l and peace on earth. These aspirations have to be transformed into demand functions and markets for specific economic artifacts such as particular goods, services and firms. Entrepreneurship consists in matching up the products of human imagination with human aspirations to create markets for goods
42、 and services that did not exist before the entrepreneurial act. In fact, most entrepreneurial opportunities, be they supply based or demand based, do not originate in the economic domain at all. For example, the internet was developed as a way to facilitate communication between defense scientists
43、and remained out of the economic domain for several years. The mere existence of the internet did not guarantee the development of e-commerce. Rather, this artifact created to solve a political problem (namely, defense), had to be transformed through several intentional and unintentional activities
44、to become a universe of entrepreneurial opportunities in the economic domain. To cite another example, entrepreneurs such as Robert Lucas transform literary and artistic endeavors into the Star Wars marketing empire by matching up creations of the human imagination with human aspirations such as the
45、 desire to participate in the triumph of good over evil. That is why if we are to understand entrepreneurial opportunities, we have to delve into the preconditions for their existence - i.e., the preconditions for the existence of demand and supply combinations that constitute entrepreneurial opport
46、unities. This leads us to a simple typology of entrepreneurial actions in relation to opportunities as follows: 1. Opportunity RecognitionIf both sources of supply and demand exist rather obviously, the opportunity for bringing them together has to be recognized and then the match-up between supply
47、and demand has to be implemented either through an existing firm or a new firm. Examples include arbitrage and franchises. For example, through its first successful coffee shop, Starbucks proved the existence of a demand for specialty coffees as also a viable and effective way to satisfy that demand
48、. Thereafter, each Starbucks franchisee only has to recognize potential geographic locations for extending that demand and supply combination. They do not have to invent sources of supply, or induce demand for a completely new product.2. Opportunity DiscoveryIf only one side exists in an obvious man
49、ner and the other side either does not exist or is so latent as to be virtually non-existent for most people - i.e., demand exists, but supply does not, and vice versa - then, the non-existent side has to be discovered before the match-up can be implemented. In other words, when demand exists; supply has to be discovered. An exampl