测量单位和函数形式-外文翻译.docx

上传人:豆**** 文档编号:29920159 上传时间:2022-08-02 格式:DOCX 页数:12 大小:115.17KB
返回 下载 相关 举报
测量单位和函数形式-外文翻译.docx_第1页
第1页 / 共12页
测量单位和函数形式-外文翻译.docx_第2页
第2页 / 共12页
点击查看更多>>
资源描述

《测量单位和函数形式-外文翻译.docx》由会员分享,可在线阅读,更多相关《测量单位和函数形式-外文翻译.docx(12页珍藏版)》请在taowenge.com淘文阁网|工程机械CAD图纸|机械工程制图|CAD装配图下载|SolidWorks_CaTia_CAD_UG_PROE_设计图分享下载上搜索。

1、河南科技学院2014届本科毕业论文(设计)英文文献及翻译UNITS OF MEASUREMENT AND FUNCTIONAL FORM学生姓名: 所在院系: 数学科学学院 所学专业: 数学与应用数学 导师姓名: 完成时间: 2013年12月25日 UNITS OF MEASUREMENT AND FUNCTIONAL FORM ( V o t i n g O u t c o m e s a n d C a m p a i g n E x p e n d i t u r e s )In the voting outcome equation in (2.28), R= 0.505. Thus,

2、 the share of campaign expenditures explains just over 50 percent of the variation in the election outcomes for this sample. This is a fairly sizable portionTwo important issues in applied economics are (1) understanding how changing theunits of measurement of the dependent and/or independent variab

3、les affects OLS estimates and (2) knowing how to incorporate popular functional forms used in economics into regression analysis. The mathematics needed for a full understanding of functional form issues is reviewed in Appendix A.The Effects of Changing Units of Measurement on OLSStatisticsIn Exampl

4、e 2.3, we chose to measure annual salary in thousands of dollars, and the return on equity was measured as a percent (rather than as a decimal). It is crucial to know how salary and roe are measured in this example in order to make sense of the estimates in equation (2.39). We must also know that OL

5、S estimates change in entirely expected ways when the units of measurement of the dependent and independent variables change. In Example2.3, suppose that, rather than measuring salary in thousands of dollars, we measure it in dollars. Let salardol be salary in dollars (salardol =845,761 would be int

6、erpreted as $845,761.). Of course, salardol has a simple relationship to the salary measured in thousands of dollars: salardol ? 1,000?salary. We do not need to actually run the regression of salardol on roe to know that the estimated equation is: salardol = 963,191 +18,501 roe. We obtain the interc

7、ept and slope in (2.40) simply by multiplying the intercept and theslope in (2.39) by 1,000. This gives equations (2.39) and (2.40) the same interpretation.Looking at (2.40), if roe = 0, then salardol = 963,191, so the predicted salary is$963,191 the same value we obtained from equation (2.39). Furt

8、hermore, if roeincreases by one, then the predicted salary increases by $18,501; again, this is what weconcluded from our earlier analysis of equation (2.39).Generally, it is easy to figure out what happens to the intercept and slope estimates when the dependent variable changes units of measurement

9、. If the dependent variable is multiplied by the constant cwhich means each value in the sample is multiplied bycthen the OLS intercept and slope estimates are also multiplied by c. (This assumes nothing has changed about the independent variable.) In the CEO salary example, c ?1,000 in moving from

10、salary to salardol.Chapter 2The Simple Regression ModelWe can also use the CEO salary example to see what happens when we change the units of measurement of the independent variable. Define roedec =roe/100 to be the decimal equivalent of roe; thus, roedec =0.23 means a return on equity of23 percent.

11、 To focus on changing the unitsof measurement of the independent variable, we return to our original dependent variable, salary, which is measured in thousands of dollars. When we regress salary onroedec, we obtain salary =963.191 + 1850.1 roedec.The coefficient on roedec is 100 times the coefficien

12、t on roe in (2.39). This is as it should be. Changing roe by one percentage point is equivalent to roedec = 0.01. From (2.41), if roedec = 0.01, then salary = 1850.1(0.01) = 18.501, which is what is obtained by using (2.39). Note that, in moving from (2.39) to (2.41), the independentvariable was div

13、ided by 100, and so the OLS slope estimate was multiplied by 100, preserving the interpretation of the equation. Generally, if the independent variable is divided or multiplied by some nonzero constant, c, then the OLS slope coefficient is also multiplied or divided by c respectively.The intercept h

14、as not changed in (2.41) because roedec =0 still corresponds to a zero return on equity. In general, changing the units of measurement of only the independent variable does not affect the intercept.In the previous section, we defined R-squared as a goodness-of-fit measure for OLS regression. We can

15、also ask what happens to R2 when the unit of measurement of either the independent or the dependent variable changes. Without doing any algebra, we should know the result: the goodness-of-fit of the model should not depend onthe units of measurement of our variables. For example, the amount of varia

16、tion in salary, explained by the return on equity, should not depend on whether salary is measured in dollars or in thousands of dollars or on whether return on equity is a percent or a decimal. This intuition can be verified mathematically: using the definition of R2, it can be shown that R2 is, in

17、 fact, invariant to changes in the units of y or x. Incorporating Nonlinearities in Simple RegressionSo far we have focused on linear relationships between the dependent and independent variables. As we mentioned in Chapter 1, linear relationships are not nearly general enough for all economic appli

18、cations. Fortunately, it is rather easy to incorporate many nonlinearities into simple regression analysis by appropriately defining the dependent and independent variables. Here we will cover two possibilities that often appear in applied work.In reading applied work in the social sciences, you wil

19、l often encounter regression equations where the dependent variable appears in logarithmic form. Why is this done? Recall the wage-education example, where we regressed hourly wage on years of education. We obtained a slope estimate of 0.54 see equation (2.27), which means that each additional year

20、of education is predicted to increase hourly wage by 54 cents.Because of the linear nature of (2.27), 54 cents is the increase for either the first year of education or the twentieth year; this may not be reasonable.Suppose, instead, that the percentage increase in wage is the same given one more ye

21、ar of education. Model (2.27) does not imply a constant percentage increase: the percentage increases depends on the initial wage. A model that gives (approximately) a constant percentage effect is log(wage) =0 +1educ + u,(2.42) where log(.) denotes the natural logarithm. (See Appendix A for a revie

22、w of logarithms.) In particular, if u =0, then %wage = (100*1) educ.(2.43) Notice how we multiply 1 by 100 to get the percentage change in wage given one additional year of education. Since the percentage change in wage is the same for each additional year of education, the change in wage for an ext

23、ra year of education increases aseducation increases; in other words, (2.42) implies an increasing return to education.By exponenttiating (2.42), we can write wage =exp(0+1educ + u). This equationis graphed in Figure 2.6, with u = 0.Estimating a model such as (2.42) is straightforward when using sim

24、ple regression. Just define the dependent variable, y, to be y = log(wage). The independent variable is represented by x = educ. The mechanics of OLS are the same as before: the intercept and slope estimates are given by the formulas (2.17) and (2.19). In other words, we obtain 0 and1 from the OLS r

25、egression of log(wage) on educ. E X A M P L E 2 . 1 0( A L o g W a g e E q u a t i o n )Using the same data as in Example 2.4, but using log(wage) as the dependent variable, we obtain the following relationship: log(wage) =0.584 +0.083 educ(2.44) n = 526, R =0.186.The coefficient on educ has a perce

26、ntage interpretation when it is multiplied by 100: wage increases by 8.3 percent for every additional year of education. This is what economists mean when they refer to the “return to another year of education.” It is important to remember that the main reason for using the log of wage in (2.42) is

27、to impose a constant percentage effect of education on wage. Once equation (2.42) is obtained, the natural log of wage is rarely mentioned. In particular, it is not correct to say that another year of education increases log(wage) by 8.3%.The intercept in (2.42) is not very meaningful, as it gives t

28、he predicted log(wage), when educ =0. The R-squared shows that educ explains about 18.6 percent of the variation in log(wage) (not wage). Finally, equation (2.44) might not capture all of the non-linearity in the relationship between wage and schooling. If there are “diploma effects,” then the twelf

29、th year of educationgraduation from high schoolcould be worth much more than the eleventh year. We will learn how to allow for this kind of nonlinearity in Chapter 7. Another important use of the natural log is in obtaining a constant elasticity model.E X A M P L E 2 . 1 1( C E O S a l a r y a n d F

30、 i r m S a l e s )We can estimate a constant elasticity model relating CEO salary to firm sales. The data set is the same one used in Example 2.3, except we now relate salary to sales. Let sales be annual firm sales, measured in millions of dollars. A constant elasticity model is log(salary =0 +1log

31、(sales) +u, (2.45) where 1 is the elasticity of salary with respect to sales. This model falls under the simple regression model by defining the dependent variable to be y = log(salary) and the independent variable to be x = log(sales). Estimating this equation by OLS gives Part 1Regression Analysis

32、 with Cross-Sectional Datalog(salary) = 4.822 ?+0.257 log(sales)(2.46)n =209, R= 0.211.The coefficient of log(sales) is the estimated elasticity of salary with respect to sales. It implies that a 1 percent increase in firm sales increases CEO salary by about 0.257 percentthe usual interpretation of

33、an elasticity.The two functional forms covered in this section will often arise in the remainder of this text. We have covered models containing natural logarithms here because they appear so frequently in applied work. The interpretation of such models will not be much different in the multiple reg

34、ression case.It is also useful to note what happens to the intercept and slope estimates if we change the units of measurement of the dependent variable when it appears in logarithmic form. Because the change to logarithmic form approximates a proportionate change, it makes sense that nothing happen

35、s to the slope. We can see this by writing the rescaled variable as c1yi for each observation i. The original equation is log(yi) =0 +1xi +ui. If we add log(c1) to both sides, we get log(c1) + log(yi) + log(c1) 0 +1xi + ui, orlog(c1yi) ? log(c1) +0 +1xi +ui.(Remember that the sum of the logs is equa

36、l to the log of their product as shown in Appendix A.) Therefore, the slope is still ?1, but the intercept is now log(c1) ? ?0. Similarly, if the independent variable is log(x), and we change the units of measurement of x before taking the log, the slope remains the same but the intercept does not c

37、hange. You will be asked to verify these claims in Problem 2.9.We end this subsection by summarizing four combinations of functional forms available from using either the original variable or its natural log. In Table 2.3, x and y stand for the variables in their original form. The model with y as t

38、he dependent variable and x as the independent variable is called the level-level model, because each variable appears in its level form. The model with log(y) as the dependent variable and x as the independent variable is called the log-level model. We will not explicitly discuss the level-log mode

39、l here, because it arises less often in practice. In any case, we will see examples of this model in later chapters.Chapter 2The Simple Regression ModelTable 2.3The last column in Table 2.3 gives the interpretation of 1. In the log-level model, 100*1 is sometimes called the semi-elasticity of y with

40、 respect to x. As we mentioned in Example 2.11, in the log-log model, 1 is the elasticity of y with respect to x. Table 2.3 warrants careful study, as we will refer to it often in the remainder of the text.The Meaning of “Linear” RegressionThe simple regression model that we have studied in this cha

41、pter is also called the simple linear regression model. Yet, as we have just seen, the general model also allows for certain nonlinear relationships. So what does “linear” mean here? You can see by looking at equation (2.1) that y =0 +1x + u. The key is that this equation is linear in the parameters

42、, 0 and 1. There are no restrictions on how y and x relate to the original explained and explanatory variables of interest. As we saw in Examples 2.7 and 2.8, y and x can be natural logs of variables, and this is quite common in applications. But we need not stop there. For example, nothing prevents

43、 us from using simple regression to estimate a model such as cons =0 +1inc+u, where cons is annual consumption and inc is annual income.While the mechanics of simple regression do not depend on how y and x are defined, the interpretation of the coefficients does depend on their definitions. For succ

44、essful empirical work, it is much more important to become proficient at interpreting coefficients than to become efficient at computing formulas such as (2.19). We will get much more practice with interpreting the estimates in OLS regression lines when we study multiple regression.There are plenty

45、of models that cannot be cast as a linear regression model because they are not linear in their parameters; an example is cons = 1/(0 +1inc) + u. Estimation of such models takes us into the realm of the nonlinear regression model, which is beyond the scope of this text. For most applications, choosi

46、ng a model that can be put into the linear regression framework is sufficient.EXPECTED VALUES AND VARIANCES OF THE OLSESTIMATORSIn Section 2.1, we defined the population model y =0 +1x +u, and we claimed that the key assumption for simple regression analysis to be useful is that the expected value o

47、f u given any value of x is zero. In Sections 2.2, 2.3, and 2.4, we discussed the algebraic properties of OLS estimation. We now return to the population model and study the statistical properties of OLS. In other words, we now view 0 and 1 as estimators for the parameters ?0 and ?1 that appear in t

48、he population model. This means that we will study properties of the distributions of ?0 and ?1 over different random samples from the population. (Appendix C contains definitions of estimators and reviews some of their important properties.)Unbiasedness of OLSWe begin by establishing the unbiasedness of OLS under a simple set of assumptions.For future reference, it is useful to number these assumptions using the prefix “SLR”for simple linear regression. The first assumption defines the population model. 测量单位和函数形式在投票结果方程(2.28)中,R= 0.505。因此,竞选支出的份额解释只是在这样的选举结果的变化百分之5

展开阅读全文
相关资源
相关搜索

当前位置:首页 > 教育专区 > 小学资料

本站为文档C TO C交易模式,本站只提供存储空间、用户上传的文档直接被用户下载,本站只是中间服务平台,本站所有文档下载所得的收益归上传人(含作者)所有。本站仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。若文档所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知淘文阁网,我们立即给予删除!客服QQ:136780468 微信:18945177775 电话:18904686070

工信部备案号:黑ICP备15003705号© 2020-2023 www.taowenge.com 淘文阁